Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (2024)

Research

Qiao Yu,

Qiao Yu Nonresident Senior Fellow

Hanwen Fan, and
HF

Hanwen Fan

Xun Wu
XW

Xun Wu

July 10, 2015

Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (2)
  • 8 min read

Content from the Brookings-Tsinghua Public Policy Center is now archived. Since October 1, 2020, Brookings has maintained a limited partnership with Tsinghua University School of Public Policy and Management that is intended to facilitate jointly organized dialogues, meetings, and/or events.

It is generally agreed that housing bubble of the United States at the turn of this century led to the unprecedented global financial crisis and subsequent great recession. Among many theories which attempt to explain reasons for the real estate bubble and the following financial crisis, the hypothesis of global saving glut suggested by Ben S. Bernanke (2005, 2007, 2009, 2010, 2011), a Distinguished Fellow at Brookings Institution and former Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, is a most influential yet controversial one.

Bernanke (2005) raised a concept of global saving glut and initially used it to account for the U.S. current account deficit. Then he (2007a, 2007b) claimed that the global saving glut “played an important role in the decline in long-term rates”. Although Bernanke (2009) did not directly attribute the financial crisis to the global saving glut, he considered that “to achieve more balanced and durable economic growth and to reduce the risks of financial instability, we must avoid ever-increasing and unsustainable imbalances in trade and capital flows”.

In January 2010, Bernanke delivered a keynote speech entitled “Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble,” at the annual American Economic Association (AEA) meeting, in which he thoroughly discussed adequacy of the Fed’s monetary policy and examined relationship between monetary policy and the rise in housing prices in the first half of the decade. Based on the evidence offered, he (2010a) concluded that the “direct linkages (between monetary policy and housing bubble), at least, are weak.” Moreover, he said, “(monetary) policy during that period—though certainly accommodative (to reduce capital flows)—does not appear to have been inappropriate……What does explain the variability in house price appreciation across countries? In my previous remarks, I have pointed out that capital flows from emerging markets to industrial countries can help to explain asset (housing) price appreciation and low long-term real interest rates in the countries receiving the funds—the so-called global saving glut.”

Bernanke (2010b) reiterated that “because large flows of capital into the United States drove down the returns available on many traditional long-term investments, such as Treasury bonds, investors’ appetite for alternative investments—such as loans to finance corporate mergers or commercial real estate projects—increased greatly in the years leading up to the crisis. These securities too were packaged and sold through the shadow banking system.” Bernanke (2010c) further explained that “a key driver of this ‘uphill’ flow of capital is official reserve accumulation in the emerging market economies that exceeds private capital in-flows to these economies. The total holdings of foreign exchange reserves by selected major emerging market economies… have risen sharply since the crisis and now surpass $5 trillion…China holds about half of the total reserves of these selected economies, slightly more than $2.6 trillion.”

Moreover, Bernanke (2011) pointed out that “the failures of the U.S. financial system in allocating strong flows of capital, both domestic and foreign, helped precipitate the recent financial crisis and global recession…A significant portion of these capital inflows reflected a broader phenomenon that, in the past, I have dubbed the global saving glut. Over the past 15 years or so, for reasons on which I have elaborated in earlier remarks, many emerging market economies have run large, sustained current account surpluses and thus have become exporters of capital to the advanced economies, especially the United States. These in-flows exacerbated the U.S. current account deficit and were also a factor pushing U.S. and global longer-term interest rates below levels suggested by expected short-term rates and other macroeconomic fundamentals.”

In sum, the global saving glut hypothesis contains a cluster of logically articulated arguments: 1) monetary policy of the U.S. Federal Reserve is appropriate prior to the financial crisis during the first decade of this century; 2) the linkage between monetary policy and housing price appreciation across industrial countries including the United States is statistically insignificant and economically weak during this period; 3) the monetary policy is accommodative to cope with capital flows from reserve-rich countries, especially developing and emerging-market nations; and 4) massive accumulation of foreign reserves and consequent capital inflows from these economies to the United States leads to low long-term real rates and housing price bubble, so as to bring about the financial crisis.

However, the literature has far from reached a consensus regarding this important assumption. On the one hand, many authors offered theoretical explanations and presented some empirical evidences in favor of the global saving glut hypothesis from various respects. For example, Caballero, Farhi and Gourinchas (2008) used a formal framework to account for central role of international financial development heterogeneity on the global imbalances and low interest rates. Warnocka and Warnockd (2009) estimated that if there were absent the substantial foreign inflows into U.S. government bonds, the long-term Treasury yield would be 80 basis points higher. Dokko et al. (2009) argued that monetary policy was not a primary factor in the housing bubble and also suspect that tighter monetary policy would not have been the best response to the bubble. Bean et al. (2010) showed that low policy rates only played a modest direct role to the growth in credit and the rise in house prices in the run‐up to the crisis. Poole (2010) pointed out that the federal policies were just supporting actors for the financial crisis but the responsibility rests primarily with the private sector. Kuttner (2012) reviewed empirical studies and concluded that impact of interest rates on house prices appears to be quite modest and the estimated effects are too small to explain the housing boom in the United States and elsewhere over the past decade. Hofmann and Bogdanova (2012) suggested that monetary policy has probably been systematically accommodative globally due to “an asymmetric reaction of monetary policy to the different stages of the financial cycle in core advanced economies, and global behavioral monetary policy spillovers through resistance to
undesired capital flows and exchange rate movements in other countries, especially in EMEs.”

On the other hand, Taylor (2007, 2009, 2010, 2012) argued that excessively low policy rates led to the housing bubble. Based on the statistical analysis, Taylor (2009) concluded that “government actions and interventions caused, prolonged, and worsened the financial crisis. They caused it by deviating from historical precedents and principles for setting interest rates, which had worked well for 20 years”. Seyfried (2010) found that loose monetary policy significantly affected housing price inflation in Ireland, Spain and the United States in the recent years. Rötheli (2010) stated that the easing monetary policy was responsible for the financial crisis and it is necessary to employ monetary policy to restrain financial boom–bust cycles in the future. Mishikin (2011) commended that “although it is far from clear that the Federal Reserve is to blame for the housing bubble, the explosion of microeconomic research, both theoretical and empirical, suggests that there is a case for monetary policy to play a role in creating credit bubbles.” Sá, Towbin and Wieladek (2011) used a panel data of the OECD countries to prove that monetary policy and capital inflows shocks had a significant and positive effect on real house prices, real credit to the private sector and real residential investment. Borio and Disyatat (2011) indicated that it was not global excess saving but credit creation, a defining feature of a monetary economy, which played a key role as main contributor to the financial crisis. Sánchez (2011) suggested that expansionary monetary policy beyond optimal rules during a long-lasting period and policies of artificially promoting credit expansion should be avoided, because they produced inadequate incentives for private sectors. McDonald and Stokes (2013) employed three alternative models and monthly data of the period 1987 to 2010 to reveal that the Federal funds rate in the U.S. had negative impacts on changes of housing prices. Based on panel data of 18 OECD countries from 1920 to 2011, Bordo, and Landon-Lane (2013) documented that loose monetary policy (either an interest rate below the target rate or a money growth rate above the target growth rate) positively affected general asset prices. This result was robust across multiple asset prices and different specifications, and it was present with other alternative explanations such as low inflation or “easy” credit controlled.

Although the above-mentioned researchers explored the issue from different perspectives, there were no decisive and convincing evidence regarding it. Therefore, more studies must be pursued to fully assess validity of the global saving glut assumption. This paper aims to provide additional evidence to verify the global saving glut hypothesis. Section I will broadly evaluate appropriation of the Fed’s monetary policy in line with the Taylor rule by using wide range of data sets. Section II will further document relationship between monetary policy and housing prices across countries. Section III will discuss linkage between the Fed’s monetary policy and foreign reserves of the East Asian export-oriented economies and the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) member countries. Section VI will search documentary clues to identify if monetary policy is accommodative to internal or external factors. Finally, Section V will provide concluding remarks.

Related Content

Why are interest rates so low, part 3: The Global Savings Glut
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (3)

Global Trade Why are interest rates so low, part 3: The Global Savings Glut

Ben S. Bernanke

April 1, 2015

Monetary Policy in 2011: Unconventional and Necessary
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (4)

U.S. Economy Monetary Policy in 2011: Unconventional and Necessary

Donald Kohn

December 14, 2011

The international monetary system: Is it fit for purpose?
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (5)

The international monetary system: Is it fit for purpose?

Eswar Prasad

October 5, 2016

Related Books

Rethinking Cyber Warfare
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (6)

Cybersecurity Rethinking Cyber Warfare

R. David Edelman

May 7, 2024

Digitally Invisible
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (7)

Digitally Invisible

Nicol Turner Lee

August 6, 2024

Lies that Kill
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (8)

Lies that Kill

Elaine Kamarck, Darrell M. West

August 27, 2024

Authors

Qiao Yu Nonresident Senior Fellow

HF

Hanwen Fan

XW

Xun Wu

More On

    Federal ReserveHousing
BPEA Spring 2022 conference

Past Event

March24-25

2022

U.S. Economy BPEA Spring 2022 conference

DC

1:00 pm - 2:00 pm EDT

Fed should keep labor markets tight for a more inclusive economy
Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (10)

U.S. Economy Fed should keep labor markets tight for a more inclusive economy

Anthony Barr, Kristen Broady

October 13, 2021

Declining competition: A transatlantic challenge

Past Event

March15

2021

Declining competition: A transatlantic challenge

Online only

9:00 am - 10:45 am EDT

Global saving glut, monetary policy, and housing bubble: Further Evidence | Brookings (2024)

FAQs

Did a global saving glut cause the US housing boom? ›

An increase in foreign credit supply (a savings glut) triggered the U.S. housing boom in the early 2000 s.

What is the global savings glut theory? ›

In sum, the global saving glut hypothesis contains a cluster of logically articulated arguments: 1) monetary policy of the U.S. Federal Reserve is appropriate prior to the financial crisis during the first decade of this century; 2) the linkage between monetary policy and housing price appreciation across industrial ...

How did the global savings glut in the 2000s affect the US current account balance? ›

This increased supply of saving boosted U.S. equity values during the period of the stock market boom and helped to increase U.S. home values during the more recent period, as a consequence lowering U.S. national saving and contributing to the nation's rising current account deficit.

How does the global savings glut help explain the trade deficit? ›

Former Federal Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke attributed the trade deficit to a "global savings glut" in which foreigners with excess savings are drawn to invest in U.S. assets because the U.S. economy offers appealing investment opportunities.

What caused the housing boom? ›

A housing or real estate bubble is a run-up in housing prices fueled by demand, speculation, and exuberant spending. Housing bubbles usually start with increased demand in the face of limited supply. Speculators further drive up demand by investing money into the market.

How did the collapse of the US housing market become a global financial crisis? ›

Defaults and foreclosure activity increased dramatically as easy initial terms expired, home prices fell, and adjustable-rate mortgage (ARM) interest rates reset higher. As housing prices fell, global investor demand for mortgage-related securities evaporated.

How does current account balance negatively impact the economy? ›

When a country runs a current account deficit, it is building up liabilities to the rest of the world that are financed by flows in the financial account. Eventually, these need to be paid back.

Which of the following best describes the effect of a global savings glut? ›

Which of the following best describes the effect of a global savings​ glut? The increased savings in the rest of the world increases international​ lending, lowering the world interest​ rate, and increasing international borrowing in the United States.

What is the reason for US current account deficit? ›

The central role of U.S. financial markets—and of the dollar—in the world economy suggests that capital account surpluses and, therefore, current account deficits are being driven primarily by foreign demand for U.S. assets rather than by any structural imbalance in the U.S. economy itself.

How does the value of the US dollar affect the US trade surplus or deficit? ›

The exchange rate of the dollar is important, as a stronger dollar makes foreign products cheaper for American consumers while making U.S. exports more expensive for foreign buyers. A growing U.S. economy also often leads to a larger deficit, since consumers have more income to buy more goods from abroad.

What is the relationship between saving in the United States and the trade deficit? ›

Is the trade deficit a problem for the U.S. economy? As discussed, trade deficits reflect the savings/investment shortfall, which means the United States is borrowing from abroad. One major concern is the debt accumulation from sustained trade deficits.

Is it better for a country to have a trade surplus or deficit? ›

Trade surpluses are no guarantee of economic health, and trade deficits are no guarantee of economic weakness. Either trade deficits or trade surpluses can work out well or poorly, depending on whether a government wisely invests the corresponding flows of financial capital.

What caused the housing boom of the 1950s? ›

As cities expanded, high land prices and crowds persuaded people and commerce alike to search for cheaper and more accommodating real estate alternatives. Following World War II, the inner cities were busting at the seams. After many years urban growth spilled over into the suburbs.

What was the major cause of the 2008 housing crisis? ›

Key Takeaways. The stock market and housing market crashes of 2008 trace their origins to the unprecedented growth of the subprime mortgage market that began in 1999. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac made home loans accessible to borrowers who had low credit scores and a higher risk of defaulting on loans.

What caused the global housing crisis? ›

Countries around the world are experiencing a housing shortage that has left millions of people homeless. The main causes of this major crisis are a depleted labor market, shortages of construction materials and worsening effects of climate change.

What were the main factors that fuelled the housing bubble in the US prior to the global financial crisis? ›

This paper discusses the four primary causes of the housing bubble—low mortgage interest rates, low short-term interest rates, relaxed standards for mortgage loans, and irrational exuberance.

References

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Aron Pacocha

Last Updated:

Views: 5921

Rating: 4.8 / 5 (68 voted)

Reviews: 91% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Aron Pacocha

Birthday: 1999-08-12

Address: 3808 Moen Corner, Gorczanyport, FL 67364-2074

Phone: +393457723392

Job: Retail Consultant

Hobby: Jewelry making, Cooking, Gaming, Reading, Juggling, Cabaret, Origami

Introduction: My name is Aron Pacocha, I am a happy, tasty, innocent, proud, talented, courageous, magnificent person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.